amazon

Richard H. Thaler “Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness”

Richard Thaler – star in behavioral economics. His book Nudge is very famous in itself., but the author himself is even more famous and you will read about it in other books on behavioral economics. Several links at once for acquaintance, and then immediately to the book itself: Richard Thaler, video, video (this video is just a fantastic example about the lines on the road), book blog.

so.

Amazon.com: What do you mean by "nudge" and why do people sometimes need to be nudged?
Thaler and Sunstein: By a nudge we mean anything that influences our choices. A school cafeteria might try to nudge kids toward good diets by putting the healthiest foods at front. We think that it’s time for institutions, including government, to become much more user-friendly by enlisting the science of choice to make life easier for people and by gentling nudging them in directions that will make their lives better.

– How this book differs from other books on behavioral finance and behavioral economics? 

– Therein, that the author (s) proposes (hut) ways to use human weaknesses against weaknesses themselves.
If you remember, Dan Ariely calls the book Predictable Irrationality, What means, that using knowledge of human error (predicting errors) you can prepare in advance and an antidote to such mistakes.
 
Part 1. People and Ecos (rational creatures from models)
In this part quickly, but it is discussed with taste, that people are not adapted to rational actions in many cases from reality. A person has two decision-making systems (slow and fast) and where speed is needed, instincts work there, who may be wrong in interpreting the messages of the modern world. It also introduces the concept of incentive (nudge) and it is being discussed, in what context it should be applied (for him to act). Immediately, the author introduces into the concept of the architecture of choice and the elements that make up the environment in which we make our choice.
 
Part 2. The money.
Here we move on to specifics – mistakes and incentives we may need. Yet again, stimulus, this is not a gingerbread that we are given for a job done right. It can be just an intuitively designed door that, by its appearance, will indicate where it needs to be pushed., from or to yourself. In this section we have: saving, investment, loans, and pensions. I will not describe in detail, see quotes below in the text.
 
Parts 3, 4: health and freedom.
I didn't get to these parts. Not because, Interestingly, take away. It's just that at the moment I am interested in social problems a little less., than the problems of specific people in the process of their work with financial markets. But you must read.
 
Part 5
Yet 12 incentives. And counterarguments about influencing people's choices.
 
In conclusion, I will write out an example, which I remembered above. About the road. So, there is a road and a turn on which few people slow down, although it needs to be done. Came up with the following. Drew lines on the road (white paint) at first at the same distance from each other (lines perpendicular to the road, like a pedestrian crossing), e.g. 50m between lines. Closer to the turn, the distance between the lines was made smaller, then even less, and very little fasting.
 
Introduce, you are driving on the road. You see lines flashing through the same time intervals. Then, lines start to flicker faster and you think, what is this from, that you start to go faster. In response, you instinctively slow down.. As a result, taking advantage of the naivety of the first decision-making system (intuitive) you were deceived and forced to slow down when entering a turn.
 
Further quotes, which I noted in the process of reading.
 
 

 

1. Carolyn is what we will be calling a choice architect. A choice architect has the responsibility for organizing the context in which people make decisions.

2. There are many parallels between choice architecture and more traditional forms of architecture. A crucial parallel is that there is no such thing as a "neutral" design.
 
3. A nudge, as we will use the term, is any aspect of the choice architecture that alters people’s behavior in a predictable way without forbidding any options or significantly changing their economic incentives. To count as a mere nudge, the intervention must be easy and cheap to avoid. Nudges are not mandates. Putting the fruit at eye level counts as a nudge. Banning junk food does
 
4. A nudge, as we will use the term, is any aspect of the choice architecture that alters people’s behavior in a predictable way without forbidding any options or significantly changing their economic incentives. To count as a mere nudge, the intervention must be easy and cheap to avoid. Nudges are not mandates. Putting the fruit at eye level counts as a nudge. Banning junk food does not.
 
5. If you look at economics textbooks, you will learn that homo economicus can think like Albert Einstein, store as much memory as IBM’s Big Blue, and exercise the willpower of Mahatma Gandhi. Really. But the folks that we know are not like that. Real people have trouble with long division if they don’t have a calculator, sometimes forget their spouse’s birthday, and have a hangover on New Year’s Day. They are not homo economicus; they are homo sapiens.
 
6. That research has raised serious questions about the rationality of many judgments and decisions that people make. To qualify as Econs, people are not required to make perfect forecasts (that would require omniscience), but they are required to make unbiased forecasts. That is, the forecasts can be wrong, but they can’t be systematically wrong in a predictable direction. Unlike Econs, Humans predictably err. Take, for example, the "planning fallacy"-the systematic tendency toward unrealistic optimism about the time it takes to complete projects. It will come as no surprise to anyone who has ever hired a contractor to learn that everything takes longer than you think, even if you know about the planning fallacy.
 
7. It seems reasonable to say that people make good choices in contexts in which they have experience, good information, and prompt feedback-say, choosing among ice cream flavors. People know whether they like chocolate, vanilla, coffee, licorice, or something else. They do less well in contexts in which they are inexperienced and poorly informed, and in which feedback is slow or infrequent-say, in choosing between fruit and ice cream (where the long-term effects are slow and feedback is poor) or in choosing among medical treatments or investment options. If you are given fifty prescription drug plans, with multiple and varying features, you might benefit from a little help.
 
8. These two figures capture the key insight that behavioral economists have borrowed from psychologists. Normally the human mind works remarkably well. We can recognize people we have not seen in years, understand the complexities of our native language, and run down a flight of stairs without falling. Some of us can speak twelve languages, improve the fanciest computers, and/or create the theory of relativity. However, even Einstein would probably be fooled by those tables. That does not mean something is wrong with us as humans, but it does mean that our understanding of human behavior can be improved by appreciating how people systematically go wrong.
 
9. How We Think: Two Systems. The workings of the human brain are more than a bit befuddling. How can we be so ingenious at some tasks and so clueless at others? Beethoven wrote his incredible ninth symphony while he was deaf, but we would not be at all surprised if we learned that he often misplaced his house keys. How can people be simultaneously so smart and so dumb? Many psychologists and neuroscientists have been converging on a description of the brain’s functioning that helps us make sense of these seeming contradictions. The approach involves a distinction between two kinds of thinking, one that is intuitive and automatic, and another that is reflective and rational.’ We will call the first the Automatic System and the second the Reflective System. (In the psychology literature, these two systems are sometimes referred to as System i and System 2, respectively.)
 
10. Ifyou are a television fan, think of Mr. Spock of Star Trek fame as someone whose Reflective System is always in control. In contrast, Homer Simpson seems to have forgotten where he put his Reflective System.
 
11. In fact, there is a great collection edited by Tom Parker titled Rules of Thumb. Parker wrote the book by asking friends to send him good rules of thumb. For example, "One ostrich egg will serve 24 people for brunch." "Ten people will raise the temperature of an average size room by one degree per hour." And one to which we will return: "No more than 25 percent of the guests at a university dinner party can come from the economics department without spoiling the conversation."
 
12. Their original work identified three heuristics, or rules of thumb-anchoring, availability, and representativeness-and the biases that are associated with each. Their research program has come to be known as the "heuristics and biases" approach to the study of human judgment. More recently, psychologists have come to understand that these heuristics and biases emerge from the interplay between the Automatic System and the Reflective System.
 
13. This process is called "anchoring and adjustment." You start with some anchor, the number you know, and adjust in the direction you think is appropriate. So far, so good. The bias occurs because the adjustments are typically insufficient.
 
14. Anchors can even influence how you think your life is going. In one experiment, college students were asked two questions: (a) How happy are you? (b) How often are you dating? When the two questions were asked in this order the correlation between the two questions was quite low (.11). But when the question order was reversed, so that the dating question was asked first, the correlation jumped to .62.
 
15. When "availability bias" is at work, both private and public decisions may be improved if judgments can be nudged back in the direction of true probabilities. A good way to increase people’s fear of a bad outcome is to remind them of a related incident in which things went wrong; a good way to increase people’s confidence is to remind them of a similar situation in which everything worked out for the best.
 
16. The third of the original three heuristics bears an unwieldy name: representativeness. Think of it as the similarity heuristic. The idea is that when asked to judge how likely it is that A belongs to category B, people (and especially their Automatic Systems) answer by asking themselves how similar A is to their image or stereotype of B (that is, how "representative" A is of B).

17. A less trivial example, from the Cornell psychologist Tom Gilovich (1991), comes from the experience of London residents during the German bombing campaigns of World War II. London newspapers published maps, such as the one shown in Figure 1.3, displaying the location of the strikes from German V-i and V-2 missiles that landed in central London. As you can see, the pattern does not seem at all random. Bombs appear to be clustered around the River Thames and also in the northwest sector of the map. People in London expressed concern at the time because the pattern seemed to suggest that the Germans could aim their bombs with great precision. Some Londoners even speculated that the blank spaces were probably the neighborhoods where German spies lived. They were wrong. In fact the Germans could do no better than aim their bombs at Central London and hope for the best. A detailed statistical analysis of the dispersion of the location of the bomb strikes determined that within London the distribution of bomb strikes was indeed random. Still, the location of the bomb strikes does not look random. What is going on here? We often see patterns because we construct our informal tests only after looking at the evidence. The World War II example is an excellent illustration of this problem. Suppose we divide the map into quadrants, as in Figure i.4-a. If we then do a formal statistical test-or, for the less statistically inclined, just count the number of hits in each quadrant-we do find evidence of a nonrandom pattern. However, nothing in nature suggests that this is the right way to test for randomness. Suppose instead we form the quadrants diagonally as in Figure i.4-b. We are now unable to reject the hypothesis that the bombs land at random. Unfortunately, we do not subject our own perceptions to such rigorous alternative testing.
 

18. Mostly, though, there is thankfully nothing to worry about, except for the fact that the use of the representativeness heuristic can cause people to confuse random fluctuations with causal patterns.
 
19. Unrealistic optimism is a pervasive feature of human life; it characterizes most people in most social categories. When they overestimate their personal immunity from harm, people may fail to take sensible preventive steps. If people are running risks because of unrealistic optimism, they might be able to benefit from a nudge. In fact, we have already mentioned one possibility: if people are reminded of a bad event, they may not continue to be so optimistic.
 
20. The combination of loss aversion with mindless choosing implies that if an option is designated as the "default," it will attract a large market share. Default options thus act as powerful nudges. In many contexts defaults have some extra nudging power because consumers may feel, rightly or wrongly, that default options come with an implicit endorsement from the default setter, be it the employer, government, or TV scheduler. For this and other reasons, setting the best possible defaults will be a theme we explore often in the course of this book.
 
21. Framing. Suppose that you are suffering from serious heart disease and that your doctor proposes a grueling operation. You’re understandably curious about the odds. The doctor says, "Of one hundred patients who have this operation, ninety are alive after five years." What will you do? If we fill in the facts in a certain way, the doctor’s statement will be pretty comforting, and you’ll probably have the operation. But suppose the doctor frames his answer in a somewhat different way. Suppose that he says, "Of one hundred patients who have this operation, ten are dead after five years." Ifyou’re like most people, the doctor’s statement will sound pretty alarming, and you might not have the operation.
 
22. Framing works because people tend to be somewhat mindless, passive decision makers. Their Reflective System does not do the work that would be required to check and see whether refraining the questions would produce a different answer. One reason they don’t do this is that they wouldn’t know what to make of the contradiction. This implies that frames are powerful nudges, and must be selected with caution.
 
23. Our goal in this chapter has been to offer a brief glimpse at human fallibility. The picture that emerges is one of busy people trying to cope in a complex world in which they cannot afford to think deeply about every choice they have to make. People adopt sensible rules of thumb that sometimes lead them astray. Because they are busy and have limited attention, they accept questions as posed rather than trying to determine whether their answers would vary under alternative formulations. The bottom line, from our point of view, is that people are, shall we say, nudge-able. Their choices, even in life’s most important decisions, are influenced in ways that would not be anticipated in a standard economic framework.
 
24. At the beginning of the dangerous curve, drivers encounter a sign painted on the road warning of the lower speed limit, and then a series of white stripes painted onto the road. The stripes do not provide much if any tactile information (they are not speed bumps) but rather just send a visual signal to drivers. When the stripes first appear, they are evenly spaced, but as drivers reach the most dangerous portion of the curve, the stripes get closer together, giving the sensation that driving speed is increasing (see Figure 1.5). One’s natural instinct is to slow down. When we drive on this familiar stretch of road, we find that those lines are speaking to us, gently urging us to touch the brake before the apex of the curve. We have been nudged.
 
25. As with Supreme Court Justice Potter Stewart’s "I know it when I see it" adage about pornography, temptation is easier to recognize than to define.
 
26. None of this means that decisions made in a cold state are always better. For example, sometimes we have to be in a hot state to overcome our fears about trying new things. Sometimes dessert really is delicious, and we do best to go for it. Sometimes it is best to fall in love. But it is clear that when we are in a hot state, we can often get into a lot of trouble.
 
27. For most of us, however, self-control issues arise because we underestimate the effect of arousal. This is something the behavioral economist George Loewenstein (1996) calls the "hot-cold empathy gap." When in a cold state, we do not appreciate how much our desires and our behavior will be altered when we are "under the influence" of arousal.
 
28. Recent research in neuroeconomics (yes, there really is such a field) has found evidence consistent with this two-system conception of self-control. Some parts of the brain get tempted, and other parts are prepared to enable us to resist temptation by assessing how we should react to the temptation.’ Sometimes the two parts of the brain can be in severe conflict-a kind of battle that one or the other is bound to lose.
 
29. The cashew problem is not only one of temptation. It also involves the type of mindless behavior we discussed in the context of inertia. In many situations, people put themselves into an "automatic pilot" mode, in which they are not actively paying attention to the task at hand. (The Automatic System is very comfortable that way.)
 
30. Since people are at least partly aware of their weaknesses, they take steps to engage outside help. We make lists to help us remember what to buy at the grocery store. We buy an alarm clock to help us get up in the morning. We ask friends to stop us from having dessert or to fortify our efforts to quit smoking. In these cases, our Planners are taking steps to control the actions of our Doers, often by trying to change the incentives that Doers face. Unfortunately, Doers are often difficult to rein in (think of controlling Homer), and they can foil the best efforts of Planners. Consider the mundane but revealing example of the alarm clock. The optimistic Planner sets the alarm for 6:15 A.M., hoping for a full day of work, but the sleepy Doer turns off the alarm and goes back to sleep until 9:oo. This can lead to fierce battles between the Planner and the Doer. Some Planners put the alarm clock on the other side of the room, so the Doer at least has to get up to turn it off, but if the Doer crawls back into bed, all is lost. Fortunately, enterprising firms sometimes offer to help the Planner out.
 
31. More formal versions of these strategies are easy to imagine. In Chapter i6 we will encounter the Web site Stickk.com (of which Karlan is a cofounder), which gives people a method by which their Planners can constrain their Doers. In some situations, people may even want the government to help them deal with their self-control problems. In extreme cases, governments might ban some items (such as heroin use, prostitution, and drunken driving). Such bans can be seen as pure rather than libertarian paternalism, though third-party interests are also at stake.
 
32. One interesting example of a government-imposed self-control strategy is daylight saving time (or summer time, as it is called in many parts of the world). Surveys reveal that most people think that daylight saving time is a great idea, primarily because they enjoy the "extra" hour of daylight during the evening. Of course, the number of daylight hours on a given day is fixed, and setting the clocks ahead one hour does nothing to increase the amount of daylight. The simple change of the labels on the hours of the day, calling "six o’clock" by the name "seven o’clock," nudges us all into waking up an hour earlier.
 
33. Alarm clocks and Christmas clubs are external devices people use to solve their self-control problems. Another way to approach these problems is to adopt internal control systems, otherwise known as mental accounting. Mental accounting is the system (sometimes implicit) that households use to evaluate, regulate, and process their home budget. Almost all of us use mental accounts, even if we’re not aware that we’re doing so.
 
34. According to economic theory (and simple logic), money is "fungible," meaning that it doesn’t come with labels. Twenty dollars in the rent jar can buy just as much food as the same amount in the food jar. But households adopt mental accounting schemes that violate fiingibility for the same reasons that organizations do: to control spending.
 
35. You can also see mental accounting in action at the casino. Watch a gambler who is lucky enough to win some money early in the evening. You might see him take the money he has won and put it into one pocket and put the money he brought with him to gamble that evening (yet another mental account) into a different pocket. Gamblers even have a term for this. The money that has recently been won is called "house money" because in gambling parlance the casino is referred to as the house. Betting some of the money that you have just won is referred to as "gambling with the house’s money," as if it were, somehow, different from some other kind of money. Experimental evidence reveals that people are more willing to gamble with money that they consider house money.4
 
36. David Gross and Nick Souleles (2002) found that the typical household in their sample had more than $S,ooo in liquid assets (typically in savings accounts earning less than S percent a year) and nearly $3,000 in credit card balances, carrying a typical interest rate of 18 percent or more. Using the money from the savings account to pay off the credit card debt amounts to what economists call an arbitrage opportunity-buying low and selling high-but the vast majority of households fail to take advantage.
 
37. that one of the most effective ways to nudge (for good or evil) is via social influence.
 
38. Social influences come in two basic categories. The first involves information. If many people do something or think something, their actions and their thoughts convey information about what might be best for you to do or think. The second involves peer pressure. If you care about what other people think about you (perhaps in the mistaken belief that they are paying some attention to what you are doing-see below), then you might go along with the crowd to avoid their wrath or curry their favor.
 
39. We can see here why many groups fall prey to what is known as "collective conservatism": the tendency of groups to stick to established patterns even as new needs arise.
 
40. The Spotlight Effect. One reason why people expend so much effort conforming to social norms and fashions is that they think that others are closely paying attention to what they are doing. If you wear a suit to a social event where everyone else has gone casual, you feel like everyone is looking at you funny and wondering why you are such a geek. If you are subject to such fears, here is a possibly comforting thought: they aren’t really paying as much attention to you as you think.
 
41. We are also greatly influenced by consumption norms within the relevant group. A light eater eats much more in a group of heavy eaters. A heavy eater will show more restraint in a light-eating group.
 
42. Priming. Thus far we have been focusing on people’s attention to the thoughts and behavior of other people. Closely related work shows the power of "priming." Priming refers to the somewhat mysterious workings of the Automatic System of the brain. Research shows that subtle influences can increase the ease with which certain information comes to mind. Imagine playing a word-association game with Homer Simpson and you will get the idea. Sometimes the merest hint of an idea or concept will trigger an association that can stimulate action. These "primes" occur in social situations, and their effects can be surprisingly powerful. In surveys, people are often asked whether they are likely to engage in certain behavior-to vote, to lose weight, to purchase certain products. Those who engage in surveys want to catalogue behavior, not to influence it. But social scientists have discovered an odd fact: when they measure people’s intentions, they affect people’s conduct. The "mere-measurement effect" refers to the finding that when people are asked what they intend to do, they become more likely to act in accordance with their answers. This finding can be found in many contexts. If people are asked whether they intend to eat certain foods, to diet, or to exercise, their answers to the questions will affect their behavior." In our parlance, the mere-measurement effect is a nudge, and it can be used by private or public nudgers.

43. The nudge provided by asking people what they intend to do can be accentuated by asking them when and how they plan to do it. This insight falls into the category of what the great psychologist Kurt Lewin called "channel factors," a term he used for small influences that could either facilitate or inhibit certain behaviors.
 

44. The three social influences that we have emphasized-information, peer pressure, and priming-can easily be enlisted by private and public nudgers.
 
45. The key point here is that for all their virtues, markets often give companies a strong incentive to cater to (and profit from) human frailties, rather than to try to eradicate them or to minimize their effects.
 
46. Suppose you are told that a group of people will have to make some choice in the near future. You are the choice architect. You are trying to decide how to design the choice environment, what kinds of nudges to offer, and how subtle the nudges should be. What do you need to know to design the best possible choice environment?
 
47. Benefits Now-Costs Later. We have seen that predictable problems arise when people must make decisions that test their capacity for self control. Many choices in life, such as whether to wear a blue shirt or a white one, lack important self-control elements. Self-control issues are most likely to arise when choices and their consequences are separated in time.
 
48. Even hard problems become easier with practice. Both of us have managed to learn how to serve a tennis ball into the service court with reasonable regularity (and in Sunstein’s case, even velocity), but it took some time.
 
49. Generally, the higher the stakes, the less often we are able to practice. Most of us buy houses and cars not more than once or twice a decade, but we are really practiced at grocery shopping. Most families have mastered the art of milk inventory control, not by solving the relevant mathematical equation but through trial and error. *
 
50. Even practice does not make perfect if people lack good opportunities for learning. Learning is most likely if people get immediate, clear feedback after each try. Suppose you are practicing your putting skills on the practice green. If you hit ten balls toward the same hole, it is easy to get a sense of how hard you have to hit the ball. Even the least talented golfers will soon learn to gauge distance under these circumstances. Suppose instead you were putting the golf balls but not getting to see where they were going. In that environment, you could putt all day and never get any better.
 
51. When feedback does not work, we may benefit from a nudge.
 
52. stimulus response compatibility. The idea is that you want the signal you receive (the stimulus) to be consistent with the desired action. When there are inconsistencies, performance suffers and people blunder.
 
53. Consider, for example, the effect of a large, red, octagonal sign that said GO.
 
54. Expect Error. Humans make mistakes. A well-designed system expects its users to err and is as forgiving as possible. Some examples from the world of real design illustrate this point: • In the Paris subway system, The Metro, users insert a paper card the size of a movie ticket into a machine that reads the card, leaves a record on the card that renders it "used," and then spits it out from the top of the machine. The cards have a magnetic strip on one side but are otherwise symmetric. On Thaler’s first visit to Paris, he was not sure how to use the system, so he tried putting the card in with the magnetic strip face up and was pleased to discover that it worked. He was careful thereafter to insert the card with the strip face up. Many years and trips to Paris later, he was proudly demonstrating to a visiting friend the correct way to use the Metro system when his wife started laughing. It turns out that it doesn’t matter which way you put the card into the machine! • Another automobile-related bit of good design involves the nozzles for different varieties of gasoline. The nozzles that deliver diesel fuel are too large to fit into the opening on cars that use gasoline, so it is not possibe to make the mistake of putting diesel fuel in your gasoline-powered car (though it is still possible to make the opposite mistake). The same principle has been used to reduce the number of errors involving anesthesia. One study found that human error (rather than equipment failure) caused 82 percent of the "critical incidents."
 
55. Give Feedback. The best way to help Humans improve their performance is to provide feedback. Well-designed systems tell people when they are doing well and when they are making mistakes. Some examples: • Digital cameras generally provide better feedback to their users than film cameras. After each shot, the photographer can see a (small) version of the image just captured. This eliminates all kinds of errors that were common in the film era, from failing to load the film properly (or at all), to forgetting to remove the lens cap, to cutting off the head of the central figure of the picture.
 
56. Incentives. Our last topic is the one with which most economists would have started: prices and incentives. Though we have been stressing factors that are often neglected by traditional economic theory, we do not intend to suggest that standard economic forces are unimportant. This is as good a point as any to state for the record that we believe in supply and demand. If the price of a product goes up, suppliers will usually produce more of it and consumers will usually want less of it. So choice architects must think about incentives when they design a system. Sensible architects will put the right incentives on the right people.
 
57. We have sketched six principles of good choice architecture. As a concession to the bounded memory of our readers, we thought it might be useful to offer a mnemonic device to help recall the six principles. By rearranging the order, and using one small fudge, the following emerges. Ncentives. Understand mappings. Defaults. Give feedback. Expect error. Structure complex choices. NUDGES. With an eye on these NUDGES, choice architects can improve the outcomes for their Human users.
 
58. The decisions they do make will differ from those of Econs in two ways. First, they will be unduly influenced by short-term fluctuations, and second, their decisions are likely to be based on rules of thumb.
 
59. The lesson from the story of Vince and Rip is that attitudes toward risk depend on the frequency with which investors monitor their portfolios.
 
60. As Kenny Rogers advises in his famous song "The Gambler": "You never count your money when you’re sittin’ at the table, / There’ll be time enough for countin’ when the dealin’s done."
 
61. Even the most sophisticated investors can sometimes find the decision about how to invest their money daunting, and they resort to simple rules of thumb. Take the example of the financial economist and Nobel laureate Harry Markowitz, one of the founders of modern portfolio theory. When asked about how he allocated his retirement account, he confessed: "I should have computed the historic covariances of the asset classes and drawn an efficient frontier. Instead … I split my contributions fifty-fifty between bonds and equities."2
 
62. Markowitz’s strategy can be viewed as one example of what might be called the diversification heuristic. "When in doubt, diversify." Don’t put all your eggs in one basket. In general, diversification is a great idea, but there is a big difference between sensible diversification and the naive kind. A special case of this rule of thumb is what might be called the "i/n" heuristic: "When faced with `n’ options, divide assets evenly across the op- tions."3 Put the same number of eggs in each basket.
 
63. In a revealing study, university employees were asked how they would invest their retirement money if they had just two funds to choose from.5 In one condition, one of the funds invested entirely in stocks, the other in bonds. Most of the participants chose to invest their money half and half, achieving an asset allocation of So percent stocks. Another group was told that one fund invested entirely in stocks and the other "balanced" fund invested half in stocks and half in bonds. People in this group could have also have invested So percent of their money in stocks by putting all their money in the balanced fiend. Instead, they followed the inn rule and divided their money evenly between the two funds-ending up with mostly stocks. People in a third group were given a choice between a balanced fund and a bond fund. Well, you can guess what they did.
 
64. We can take some general lessons from this analysis. When markets get more complicated, unsophisticated and uneducated shoppers will be especially disadvantaged by the complexity. The unsophisticated shoppers are also more likely to be given bad or self interested advice by people serving in roles that appear to be helpful and purely advisory. In this market, mortgage brokers who cater to rich clients probably have a greater incentive to establish a reputation for fair dealing. By contrast, mortgage brokers who cater to the poor are often more interested in making a quick buck.*
 
65. We have covered a number of topics in this chapter, but the unifying message is simple. For mortgages, school loans, and credit cards, life is far more complicated than it needs to be, and people can be exploited. Often it’s best to ask people to take care of themselves, but when people borrow, standard human frailties can lead to serious hardship and even disaster. Here as elsewhere, government should respect freedom of choice; but with a few improvements in choice architecture, people would be far less likely to choose badly.

 

Amazon Kindle, why, why and how

tasks that were:
1) read many books that are freely available from the monitor screen;
2) English language, although they say, that by simple steps you can read in Russian;

why exactly Kindle:
1) Amazon, I like working with him. I don't know anything else)
2) Spontaneity of decision making. For example, I ordered without 3G, thinking, that will not work in Ukraine))))
3) Critical characteristics: upload your files, take notes and bookmarks Kindle has.
4) Price. The cheapest due to the weak initial configuration. Why pay more.

And How:
1) Perfectly readable from the screen. Really like paper to the eyes.
2) With a book in Kindle format, there are no problems at all, although the graphs are displayed on a solid four.
3) PDF is not convenient to read without processing and transfer to the Kindle format.
4) With a little effort, you can transform DPF into an addable format.
5) Reading functionality: did not invent, what would be missing.

additional features:
1) Browser as browser, in principle, you can go to any site. For example FT can be read by changing the screen layout from vertical to horizontal (good for PDF too).
2) Music. Excellent sound quality. Really very good. Didn't figure it out with the player, probably he is not. Ie. navigation is not very convenient. Audiobooks can be dropped on it and listened to too. There is a headphone output.
3) Reading text with voice. Probably to the maximum possible. If the book has good punctuation, then you can really listen to that, how he reads the written text. And, you can take DPF, format it correctly, overtake the Kindle format and ask him to read and he will do it) For example, I have several books, which I would like to run fast (what they write about trading for dummies), it is quite possible to do it. Ie. in fact, you can make an audiobook from ordinary DPF. Of course, it cannot be compared with a reading person., especially with Kramer, but for certain the situation will really go.

Important.
You won't cut costs on the cost of books.  Except on delivery.
Well, the delivery time. A week versus a few seconds)

Валентин Гроголь: «Профессионал зарабатывает, а любитель – играет»

– Who is a trader?

– Traders – it is a separate elite cohort in any bank or financial company. It happens, that professionals make millions for their organization, а иногда – bankrupt her completely. A striking example – infamous Nick Lisson, the loser of over a billion dollars of the largest English bank, whom the queen herself trusted with her savings. Hedge Fund Manager John Paulson, vice versa, earned billions of dollars during the last crisis, playing down. Том Болдуин, which scalps the market with huge positions, earns hundreds of millions of dollars, and he started with his own money, trading with just one lot.

In general, the times of crushing losses and millions “jackpots” for corporate traders have long passed. To date “nuts” control over traders tightened to the limit. The risk management system is now built as follows, what if someone even really wanted to repeat “feats” Nika Lisson, then it would be impossible. The system automatically blocks the trader, if the level of his losses has exceeded the previously agreed rates. If a trader works with his own money, then that's another story: he is his own boss and there are examples of amazing ups and downs. What is Jess Livermore worth, who made millions from practically nothing during the year, and then in a few weeks lost everything. After that Livermore sold his wife's jewelry, At home, borrowed and again a year later became a dollar millionaire.

80% successful traders do not manage their money, and by means of large trading companies and work under the supervision of professionals. Statistics show that, what in 70% cases, when the trader is on his own, he takes unnecessary risks, which is fraught with big losses.

– What do you control now??

– Now I manage the money of the Omikron corporation, operating in hundreds of thousands of dollars. List of shares, с которыми я работаю, not static. With the help of special screening programs, among thousands of shares, you can find exactly those, that match your trading style. If earlier it was possible to select a portfolio from 10-20 shares and trade it for 2-3 Months, then today in conditions of increased volatility, once a 2-3 day the portfolio has to be revised and adjusted. For me, the most important thing is not the industry, and liquidity, the presence of noise on the action, number of events, risk-reward ratio.

Average trader's turnover, under whose control is $150-200 thousand, is $10 million. a day is about $200 million. per month. And there are tens of thousands of us. Вот и представьте, what money is spinning in the industry. It is we who enable the "big fish" to buy and sell large blocks of shares in a short time, receiving a small reward for it.

-What instruments do you speculate with, and what place among them are the securities of the banking sector?

– There are so many instruments in the American markets, что бывает такое, that you catch yourself thinking, what do you trade with a tool, который тебе подходит, but you understand very distantly, чем вообще занимается эта компания.

The most important thing is not the industry, and liquidity, the presence of noise on the action, number of events, risk-reward ratio. По моему субъективному мнению, the banking sector is the most dangerous, as it is poorly subject to technical analysis and extremely emotional. However, among the shares of companies, which I trade, still there are people like, for example, Morgan Stanley (ticker MS), which is listed on the New York Stock Exchange. This instrument has frequent entry signals., a little noise, but the risk at the breaking point is higher, than Wells Fargo, which does not have these terrible candlestick tails and emissions on breakouts of significant levels.

Another famous Credit Suisse sometimes behaves very well.. And there are days, when the securities of this company are dead and give absolutely no signals to enter or exit. We select stocks based on historical data, but we understand whether it is possible to work with them only during the session. Может быть такое, that yesterday the paper gave a lot of opportunities to earn, and today we need it “take a vacation”.

Deutsche Bank is usually in a good trading range, but I find it difficult to analyze supply and demand in Level2. Can, certainly, and without it, but without this tool the chances of success are reduced.

HSBS (ticker HBC) - good volumes, but the entry signal is usually never confirmed, that is, you need to immediately make a decision. It has no transient state, растет вверх, and then "bangs" down. But there is little noise and a fairly accurate tilt angle, if more 45% up, then in no case should you think about opening short positions.

Citi Bank is not good for intraday speculation, as it has a too low denomination and the trader will go broke on commissions. Potential movements that are too small are associated with this., I naturally mean in cent, not in percentage terms

– Everyone is interested, how much can a trader earn in “prime of life”. How much do you get?

– Let's start with this, what am I, as a specialist, I am very expensive. For example, already in 25 years I became the winner of international trading competitions. Add to this an impeccable reputation, which I support for a long time, which in itself is also very difficult. Knowledge helps me in my work, received in universities. I graduated from the Faculty of Economics, Moscow State University, and then – MBA in Investment Management at the Higher School of Economics. Education and experience – this is the basis of work in the field of trust management.

Like any professional, I went to success in stages. In the beginning, I received 50% income from the amount given to me in management, but for today i take 98%. The company is enough 2%. After all, for the organization – this is secondary income. Her main profit is part of the commission, which the broker returns. The company will never go to waste. The organization, which work according to this scheme, are considered very reliable, as for them the risks of bankruptcy are extremely small.

Trading – this is a highly profitable profession. Logically, what's on the exchange, if one wins, means, someone else – loses. But I don't see anything wrong with that: eventually – it's just business. Standard competition laws apply here – the best profit. Nobody bothers outsiders to improve their professionalism, for example, in trading schools, and stand out in the ranks of the winners.

– Is it difficult to become a professional trader?

– The hardest part – it is to learn to apply knowledge in time, while controlling your emotions. The big problem is, that you can't take someone else's experience and use it. For different people, the same stock can be overly fast., it will be difficult to make a decision on it, so too slow. Than short-term speculation, the more important is the experience and skills gained. To an extent – it's a trial and error. But the road to success will be shorter, if there is an experienced comrade nearby.

The beauty and horror of day trading at the same time is, that in order to master this profession you do not need to graduate from specialized institutes. To understand whether you can master this profession or not, just get the necessary knowledge, practice mnemonic skills and trade.

A foundation of theoretical knowledge for mastering the profession of an intraday trader, fits into two workshops on 5 hours. The rest of the time is practice on virtual accounts and hone your skills.. It can take from a week to months or even – years in difficult cases. Now Stock Trading School is negotiating with the Omikron trading corporation, so that she gives the best graduates of Stock Trading School money for management without making a risk deposit or minimizing it. Naturally, to get a recommendation from us, taking a forty-five hour course "Professional Day Trader" will not be enough. You still need to trade from our dealing rooms on virtual accounts under our guidance. The trader must gain experience, and we – statistics of his operations. With its help, we will be able to find the weak and strong points of the trader and together choose the exact style of trading., which suits and will bring money to this particular specialist. In trading, there are no universal solutions for everyone and everything is highly personalized.. So the only approach is, fruitful, – this is an individual training, основанный на том, how the trader perceived and reproduces that information, which he received in the first ten hours of theoretical studies.

– Little of, that you work simultaneously in several organizations at once, but you are also heading School of trading on American stock exchanges (Stock Trading School). Is it difficult for you to combine work with teaching?

– I only teach in my free time from trading. During my work, I show by personal example the algorithm of actions of a professional trader.. In addition to me, the school also has successful and experienced traders and teachers., who constantly monitor and help beginners. More and more of us, as successful traders switch from Russian exchanges to American ones. I have never seen the reverse process..

Besides, we have released two video courses on active professional trading. We did this to facilitate the learning process.. Many additionally require an alternative to live seminars form of information submission. In a live lesson, you can accidentally miss something, do not have time to write down or just forget. Eventually you can be late for the seminar. And an additional video course will refresh your knowledge and fill in the gaps. The only thing, what you need after studying our video courses, – it is to gain experience, first on a virtual account, and then – на денежном. This is also best done under the supervision of professionals..

Our video courses – it is the foundation for successful trading. Having studied them, all that remains is to gain experience. It can be free, if you stick with that, what did you learn in the video course, or can cost a pretty penny. The market is a great teacher, who does not forgive negligence and punishes those, who doesn't work, but just playing. This is the main difference between a professional trader and an amateur.. Professional earns, and an amateur – plays, like in a casino.

– Crisis triggered a wave of allegations of fraud in securities trading and fund management in the West. Is it true?, that professional traders are often tempted to engage in scams?

The reason is rather not some malicious intent on the part of traders., rather, in the unjustified excitement of some hedge funds, which allow traders to take on increased risks. As for the acclaimed Goldman Sachs scandal (paper, prohibited for trading in most dealing rooms), then this is due to the wrong, that they were accused or suspected of something, а с тем, that the average risk / reward ratio is unacceptable for the intraday trader. The beginning of the session there is generally a disaster and is more like gambling in a casino., than to work. Whatever the scandals in the American stock markets, they remain the most transparent and honest. This is one of the main reasons, why 99,9% professional traders choose NYSE , AMEX, NASDAQ. At these sites, everyone has equal opportunities to work and earn money.. There is no insider factor here, does not allow to work normally on Russian and other developing exchanges and even some platforms of developed countries.

– Agree with the opinion of the information portal “My finances”, that you are ripping the stock market bread out of grasping American teeth?

– I need to make money and I do it. Then you might as well say, that a more experienced surgeon will take money away from a less experienced one. So you can get to the point of absurdity. Trading – it is one of the few industries, where you can get decent rewards at an early age. Overall, it's like a sport, that is, a profession for young. Although, there are exceptions. Nevertheless, if you have a good high-paying job, do not leave her immediately after, how did you make your first thousand dollars. Different time zones between Russia and the USA allow you to try yourself as a trader in the evening, because American markets open in 17.30 and close at midnight Moscow time. Nevertheless, I can not but rejoice that, that among my students there have already appeared those, for whom trading is the main income. We are now deciding, where will we trade in summer: in Bali or on the Cote d'Azur. Our work is not tied to a specific place. The only thing, what we need – these are computers, stable working internet and close people around.

“My favorite stocks”
NYSE

XOM Exxon Mobil Corp
V Visa Inc
WMT Wal-Mart Stores Inc
TOT Total SA
TM Toyota Motor Corp
TIF Tiffany&Co
SLB Shlumberger Limited
SNE Sony Corp
SI Siemens AG
SAP SAP AG
RY Royal Bank of Canada
RNR Renaissancere Holding
REP Repsol YPF SA
PM Philip Morris
PG The Procter & Gamble
PEP PepsiCo Inc
NKE NIKE Inc
MCD McDonald
MAR Marriott
KO Coca-Cola
JNJ Johnson&Johnson
HSY Hershey
HPQ Hewlett-Packard
HOG Harley-Davison
HMC Honda
HLF Herbalife
FDX FedEx
DB Deutsche Bank
COP ConocoPhilips
CAT Caterpillar
BHP BHP Billiton
BA Boeing

NASDAQ

SBUX Starbucks
ORCL Oracle
MSFT Microsoft
AMZN Amazon.com
AAPL Apple
AMEX
SPY
GLD
BTI British American Tobacco
DIG Ultra Oil & Gas ProShares

AMEX

BTI (British American Tobacco), SPY, SSO, SDS, FAS, DOES

and many others.

A source: bankir.ru

Business Audiobooks – a selection of food for the mind

First on the list we have an interesting person named Donald and with the last name Trump. Do you know who he is? Not? And what is Trump Tower you know? Picture, Viki. Donald Trump's first book is called “The art of making deals” , I recommend reading, although the name may scare you away. But don't be intimidated by this name., this is a very useful book. Donald Trump – How to get rich – also recommend reading. Donald Trump – Think like a billionaire – also a very good book, many useful tips specifically for thinking. In some places, Trump is very arrogant and it can be seen that he loves himself a lot., but if you ignore it – very useful books. And in general, – he has the right to be proud of himself – built a huge empire.

I'm not a pessimist – I'm a realist

“I'm sure, that Amazon will grow significantly next month”, Tom tells his buddy Fred during a coffee break. “Why do you think that??”, Fred asks skeptically. Tom answers: “classes start next month, and students and teachers will need to buy books; this should increase sales, which means, and share price. ” Fred objects: “Maybe, but it may not be so easy. This is just one of many possible factors., and the price may depend on many other reasons, which you probably missed”. Disappointed with poor support from a friend, Tom screams, “You are such a pessimist”.

I am not a pessimist – I am a realist

“I’m sure that Amazon in the next month will rise considerably,” said Tom to his friend Fred during the coffee break. “Why do you think so?” Skeptically asked Fred. Tom says: “in next month’s classes begin, but students and teachers need to buy books, it should increase sales, and hence the share price.” Fred retorts: “Maybe, but it might not be so easy. This is just one of many possible factors, but the price may depend on a number of other reasons that you probably missed. Disillusioned little support for his friend, Tom yells, “You’re such a pessimist.”

Barnes and Noble, Inc. (New York Stock Exchange)

Company’s principal business is the sale of trade books (generally hardcover and paperback consumer titles, excluding educational textbooks and specialized religious titles), mass-market paperbacks (such as mystery, romance, science fiction and other fiction), children’s books, bargain books, magazines, gift, cafe products and services, music and movies direct to customers. As of January 31, 2009, the Company operated 778 bookstores and a Website. Of the 778 bookstores, 726 operate under the Barnes & Noble Booksellers trade name and 52 operate primarily under the B. Dalton Bookseller trade name. As of January 31, 2009, the Company owned an approximate 74% interest in Calendar Club, an operator of seasonal kiosks. The Company subsequently sold its interest in Calendar Club in February 2009. In March 2009, the Company acquired Fictionwise. Barnes & Noble conducts the online part of its business through barnesandnoble.com llc (Barnes & Noble.com). Through Sterling Publishing Co., Inc. (Sterling), the Company is a general trade book publisher. Barnes & Noble stores range in size from 10,000 to 60,000 square feet depending upon market size, with an overall average store size of 26,000 square feet. Most of the Company’s B. Dalton stores range in size from 2,000 to 6,000 square feet. B. …

Barnes and Noble, Inc. (New York Stock Exchange) Читать далее

Scroll to Top